Research

Earnings instability: The hidden volatility of American workers' paychecks

September 30, 2025

Executive summary

For many workers, steady employment does not lead to steady income. While workers’ annual incomes and hourly wages are relatively stable, new research using JPMorganChase Institute data finds that workers’ incomes vary considerably month-to-month. This is a source of significant financial risk for many households: unpredictable paychecks make it hard to plan spending and bill payments and can make households less resilient to unplanned expenses. 

The research finds:

  1. Hourly workers experience a lot of instability: their typical month-to-month change in earnings is 9 percent, but 1 in 4 months sees a bigger monthly swing of at least 21 percent, which is often larger than these workers’ checking account balances.
  2. Employer-specific factors cause most earnings volatility: fluctuating product demand, idiosyncratic scheduling decisions, etc.
  3. Earnings instability is costly for workers: 25 percent of earnings instability is passed through to spending instability, and the typical hourly worker would give up to 11 percent of their income to have the same stability as a salaried worker.

 

These findings imply that a worker’s employment status and annual income can belie significant financial insecurity—two workers with the same annual income but different amounts of earnings stability may face very different financial risks. Moreover, this month-to-month earnings instability is nearly impossible to detect in the annual data used by most analysts. Finally, because workers are more likely to quit jobs with less earnings stability, increasing the stability of workers’ earnings could benefit both workers and employers. 

There are many reasons why a worker’s hours and paycheck might change from one pay period to the next. An employer might schedule a worker for fewer hours than normal. A worker might be sick or give a shift to a co-worker to care for their child. How much does this instability in earnings cost workers? If instability is rare, or driven mostly by workers’ own desire for flexibility, it may not be costly at all. If earnings instability is common and driven more by employers’ needs or choices, it could impose significant costs on workers. When pay is unpredictable, it becomes harder to prioritize bill payments and more generally plan future spending. Institute research has previously found that many households rely on their discretionary income to deal with emergency expenses. Unexpected disruptions to discretionary income could leave a household financially vulnerable. 

New research by JPMorganChase Institute fellows at the University of Chicago provides evidence that earnings instability is common among hourly workers, is driven primarily by employers, and is very costly. Workers value earnings stability, and when employers can find solutions to reduce earnings instability, it can benefit both workers and employers. Read the full report here.

Finding 1: Earnings are extremely volatile for hourly workers.

While a worker’s hourly wage only changes, on average, once every 10 months, their take-home pay changes in 7 out of every 10 months, even while staying at the same job. This month-to-month take-home pay can be unpredictable, as these changes in monthly earnings are negative about as often as they are positive (Figure 1). For hourly workers, the typical monthly change is 9 percent, but larger changes are also common. One in 4 months sees a change of 21 percent or more, and these changes are frequently larger than the worker’s typical checking account balance.

Fortunately, earnings instability is not very persistent: if a worker’s earnings drop suddenly in a given month, they have a high chance of bouncing back quickly. These changes are typically short-term shocks that do not carry over from one year to the next. However, this means detecting earnings instability is nearly impossible using annual data, which is much more commonly available than the monthly earnings data used here. As a result, standard annual income measures may give the impression of stability, while workers are actually navigating frequent financial ups and downs.

Figure 1: Month-to-month changes in hourly workers’ pay are rarely zero and often negative.

This figure is a histogram titled “Share of hourly workers’ months with the given change in monthly income.” It shows how often hourly workers experience different magnitudes of month-to-month income changes, measured as the percent change in average monthly pay per paycheck relative to the median of the prior three months. The horizontal axis lists seven income-change categories, and the vertical axis shows the share of months (percent) falling into each category.

Income-change categories and their corresponding shares of months:

  • More than 30% decrease: 3%
  • 10% to 30% decrease: 12%
  • 0% to 10% decrease: 27%
  • No change: 10%
  • 0% to 10% increase: 29%
  • 10% to 30% increase: 14%
  • More than 30% increase: 6%

Figure note: Because workforce sample sizes vary month to month, volatility is defined as the percent change in earnings in the current month compared with the median earnings of the three months prior.
Source: Ganong, Noel, Patterson, Vavra, and Weinberg. 2025. “Earnings Instability.”

Finding 2: Employers drive most earnings volatility.

For most workers, regular seasonal fluctuations in the labor market do not explain the significant earnings instability observed in the data, nor does unpaid leave hourly workers may take to care for family or go on vacation. The majority of earnings instability appears to be driven by employers. Employers frequently change the total number of hours they demand from workers—if a manufacturing firm gets an unusually small number of orders, all workers may get their hours cut—and this accounts for roughly half of workers’ earnings instability. Idiosyncratic scheduling also contributes significantly—that is, the firm needs the same amount of labor every month but any specific worker’s schedule changes from month to month.

Finding 3: Earnings instability is costly for workers.

How much does earnings instability cost workers? One way to measure the cost is by looking at consumption. If a worker can fully adapt to and anticipate the fluctuations in their earnings, it suggests that instability imposes very little inconvenience. However, the data show that almost a quarter of earnings instability is passed through to workers’ spending. When earnings instability increases 10 percentage points, spending instability increases by 2.3 percentage points.

Another way to measure the costs of earnings instability is to compare how much workers prefer low-volatility employers to high-volatility ones based on job quit rates and wage differentials. How often are workers willing to take a job with more stability even though it pays a little less? The research finds that workers are more likely to quit more volatile employers. The revealed preference of workers for jobs with more stability makes it possible to estimate directly how much workers value stability. Estimates in the report suggest that the typical hourly worker would accept a pay cut of 4–11 percent to have the same volatility as the typical salaried worker. That is, reducing schedule and earnings uncertainty is as valuable to workers as a moderate pay raise.

Conclusion and implications

Taken together, these findings point to broader implications for financial security and inequality, with important considerations for workers, firms, and policymakers.

  • Employment status and annual income are often used as a proxy for a worker’s financial security. However, these findings suggest that two workers with the same annual income, but different earnings instability, also face different financial risks. The worker with less stability may be less able to cope with unexpected expenses, and so they may need to keep more in their emergency savings fund and/or more access to short-term credit to stay financially secure.
  • These findings also suggest that decreasing earnings instability could be a significant opportunity for firms to provide a mutually beneficial amenity to workers. When workers prefer a more stable job even if it pays slightly less than a less stable alternative, an employer who improves job stability can better meet worker preferences, strengthening worker retention and satisfaction while aligning compensation with what workers value most. However, it is also important to note that a significant share of employer-driven instability may be unavoidable. For example, if a caterer receives an unusually low number of orders for the coming month, it may not be able to give its employees as many hours as usual. For such industries, other means of improving financial security will be important for workers, such as increased savings, improved financial education, and maintaining credit access.
  • Finally, because instability is costly and more common for lower income workers, these findings suggest that measures of income inequality will understate welfare inequality. If the wages of low-income workers improve relative to high-income, income inequality falls. But if those wage gains are also accompanied by increases in earnings instability, the welfare of low-income workers may actually decrease relative to high-income workers. 

This material is a product of JPMorganChase Institute and is provided to you solely for general information purposes. Unless otherwise specifically stated, any views or opinions expressed herein are solely those of the authors listed and may differ from the views and opinions expressed by J.P. Morgan Securities LLC (JPMS) Research Department or other departments or divisions of JPMorgan Chase & Co. or its affiliates. This material is not a product of the Research Department of JPMS. Information has been obtained from sources believed to be reliable, but JPMorgan Chase & Co. or its affiliates and/or subsidiaries (collectively J.P. Morgan) do not warrant its completeness or accuracy. Opinions and estimates constitute our judgment as of the date of this material and are subject to change without notice. No representation or warranty should be made with regard to any computations, graphs, tables, diagrams or commentary in this material, which is provided for illustration/reference purposes only. The data relied on for this report are based on past transactions and may not be indicative of future results. J.P. Morgan assumes no duty to update any information in this material in the event that such information changes. The opinion herein should not be construed as an individual recommendation for any particular client and is not intended as advice or recommendations of particular securities, financial instruments, or strategies for a particular client. This material does not constitute a solicitation or offer in any jurisdiction where such a solicitation is unlawful.

We are thankful to the many people who made essential contributions to this research. The data and analyses presented in this report were prepared by Daniel M. Sullivan. 

In addition, we are indebted to our internal partners and colleagues, who support delivery of our agenda in a myriad of ways and acknowledge their contributions to each and all releases.

Media Contact
Shelby Wagenseller, 
Shelby.Wagenseller@jpmchase.com